Jump to content

Mutual majority criterion

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

The mutual majority criterion is a criterion for evaluating electoral systems. It is also known as the majority criterion for solid coalitions and the generalized majority criterion. This criterion requires that whenever a majority of voters prefer a group of candidates above all others, then the winner must be a candidate from that group.[1] The mutual majority criterion may also be thought of as the single-winner case of Droop-Proportionality for Solid Coalitions.

Formal definition

[edit]

Let L be a subset of candidates. A solid coalition in support of L is a group of voters who strictly prefer all members of L to all candidates outside of L. In other words, each member of the solid coalition ranks their least-favorite member of L higher than their favorite member outside L. Note that the members of the solid coalition may rank the members of L differently.

The mutual majority criterion says that if there is a solid coalition of voters in support of L, and this solid coalition consists of more than half of all voters, then the winner of the election must belong to L.

Relationships to other criteria

[edit]

This is similar to but stricter than the majority criterion, where the requirement applies only to the case that L is only one single candidate. It is also stricter than the majority loser criterion, which only applies when L consists of all candidates except one.[2]

All Smith-efficient Condorcet methods pass the mutual majority criterion.[3]

Methods which pass mutual majority but fail the Condorcet criterion may nullify the voting power of voters outside the mutual majority whenever they fail to elect the Condorcet winner.

By method

[edit]

Anti-plurality voting, range voting, and the Borda count fail the majority-favorite criterion and hence fail the mutual majority criterion.

The Schulze method, ranked pairs, instant-runoff voting, Nanson's method, and Bucklin voting pass this criterion.

Borda count

[edit]
Majority criterion#Borda count

The mutual majority criterion implies the majority criterion so the Borda count's failure of the latter is also a failure of the mutual majority criterion. The set solely containing candidate A is a set S as described in the definition.

Minimax

[edit]

Assume four candidates A, B, C, and D with 100 voters and the following preferences:

19 voters 17 voters 17 voters 16 voters 16 voters 15 voters
1. C 1. D 1. B 1. D 1. A 1. D
2. A 2. C 2. C 2. B 2. B 2. A
3. B 3. A 3. A 3. C 3. C 3. B
4. D 4. B 4. D 4. A 4. D 4. C

The results would be tabulated as follows:

Pairwise election results
X
A B C D
Y A [X] 33
[Y] 67
[X] 69
[Y] 31
[X] 48
[Y] 52
B [X] 67
[Y] 33
[X] 36
[Y] 64
[X] 48
[Y] 52
C [X] 31
[Y] 69
[X] 64
[Y] 36
[X] 48
[Y] 52
D [X] 52
[Y] 48
[X] 52
[Y] 48
[X] 52
[Y] 48
Pairwise election results (won-tied-lost): 2-0-1 2-0-1 2-0-1 0-0-3
worst pairwise defeat (winning votes): 69 67 64 52
worst pairwise defeat (margins): 38 34 28 4
worst pairwise opposition: 69 67 64 52
  • [X] indicates voters who preferred the candidate listed in the column caption to the candidate listed in the row caption
  • [Y] indicates voters who preferred the candidate listed in the row caption to the candidate listed in the column caption

Result: Candidates A, B and C each are strictly preferred by more than the half of the voters (52%) over D, so {A, B, C} is a set S as described in the definition and D is a Condorcet loser. Nevertheless, Minimax declares D the winner because its biggest defeat is significantly the smallest compared to the defeats A, B and C caused each other.

Plurality

[edit]

Tennessee and its four major cities: Memphis in the far west; Nashville in the center; Chattanooga in the east; and Knoxville in the far northeast

Suppose that Tennessee is holding an election on the location of its capital. The population is concentrated around four major cities. All voters want the capital to be as close to them as possible. The options are:

  • Memphis, the largest city, but far from the others (42% of voters)
  • Nashville, near the center of the state (26% of voters)
  • Chattanooga, somewhat east (15% of voters)
  • Knoxville, far to the northeast (17% of voters)

The preferences of each region's voters are:

42% of voters
Far-West
26% of voters
Center
15% of voters
Center-East
17% of voters
Far-East
  1. Memphis
  2. Nashville
  3. Chattanooga
  4. Knoxville
  1. Nashville
  2. Chattanooga
  3. Knoxville
  4. Memphis
  1. Chattanooga
  2. Knoxville
  3. Nashville
  4. Memphis
  1. Knoxville
  2. Chattanooga
  3. Nashville
  4. Memphis


58% of the voters prefer Nashville, Chattanooga and Knoxville to Memphis. Therefore, the three eastern cities build a set S as described in the definition. But, since the supporters of the three cities split their votes, Memphis wins under plurality voting.

See also

[edit]

References

[edit]
  1. ^ Green-Armytage, James (2004). "Cardinal-weighted pairwise comparison" (PDF). Voting matters. Retrieved 2024-10-19.
  2. ^ Tideman, Nicolaus (2006). Collective Decisions and Voting: The Potential for Public Choice. Ashgate Publishing. ISBN 978-0-7546-4717-1. Note that mutual majority consistency implies majority consistency.
  3. ^ Green-Armytage, James (October 2011). "Four Condorcet-Hare Hybrid Methods for Single-Winner Elections" (PDF). Voting Matters. No. 29. pp. 1–14. S2CID 15220771. Meanwhile, they possess Smith consistency [efficiency], along with properties that are implied by this, such as [...] mutual majority.